Jacobi polynomials: Difference between revisions
No edit summary |
|||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
In [[economics]], '''labor demand''' refers to the number of hours of hiring that an employer is willing to do based on the various [[Exogenous variables|exogenous]] (externally determined) variables it is faced with, such as the [[wage rate]], the unit cost of [[Capital (economics)|capital]], the market-determined selling price of its output, etc. The function specifying the quantity of labor that would be demanded at any of various possible values of these exogenous variables is called the '''labor demand function'''.<ref>[[Hal Varian|Varian, Hal]], 1992, ''Microeconomic Analysis'', 3rd Ed., W.W. Norton & Company, Inc. New York.</ref> | |||
==Perfect competitor== | |||
The labor demand function of a [[Perfect competition|competitive firm]] is determined by the following [[profit maximization]] problem: | |||
:<math> \text{Maximize} \,\, pQ - wL - rK \,\, \text{with respect to} \,\, Q, \, L, \, \text{and} \, K</math> | |||
:<math> \text{subject to} </math> | |||
:<math>Q = f\,(L, K),</math> | |||
where ''p'' is the exogenous selling price of the produced output, ''Q'' is the chosen quantity of output to be produced per month, ''w'' is the hourly wage rate paid to a worker, ''L'' is the number of labor hours hired (the quantity of labor demanded) per month, ''r'' is the cost of using a machine (capital) for an hour (the "rental rate"), ''K'' is the number of hours of machinery used (the quantity of capital demanded) per month, and ''f'' is the [[production function]] specifying the amount of output that can be produced using any of various combinations of quantities of labor and capital. This optimization problem involves simultaneously choosing the levels of labor, capital, and output. The resulting labor demand, capital demand, and output supply functions are of the general form | |||
:<math> L(p, w, r),</math> | |||
:<math> K(p, w, r),</math> | |||
and | |||
:<math> Q(p, w, r).</math> | |||
Ordinarily labor demand will be an increasing function of the product's selling price ''p'' (since a higher ''p'' makes it worthwhile to produce more output and to hire additional units of input in order to do so), and a decreasing function of ''w'' (since more expensive labor makes it worthwhile to hire less labor and produce less output). The rental rate of capital, ''r'', has two conflicting effects: more expensive capital induces the firm to substitute away from physical capital usage and into more labor usage, contingent on any particular level of output; but the higher capital cost also induces the firm to produce less output, requiring less usage of both inputs. Depending on which effect predominates, labor demand could be either increasing or decreasing in ''r''. | |||
==Monopolist== | |||
If the firm is a [[monopolist]], its optimization problem is different because it cannot take its selling price as given: the more it produces, the lower will be the price it can obtain for each unit of output, according to the market [[demand curve]] for the product. So its profit-maximization problem is | |||
:<math> \text{Maximize} \,\, pQ(p) - wL - rK \,\, \text{with respect to} \, L, \, K, \, \text{and} \, p</math> | |||
:<math> \text{subject to} </math> | |||
:<math>Q(p) = f\,(L, K),</math> | |||
where ''Q''(''p'') is the market demand function for the product. The constraint equates the amount that can be sold to the amount produced. Here labor demand, capital demand, and the selling price are the choice variables, giving rise to the input demand functions | |||
:<math> L(w, r),</math> | |||
:<math> K(w, r),</math> | |||
and the pricing function | |||
:<math> p(w, r).</math> | |||
There is no output supply function for a monopolist, because a supply function pre-supposes the existence of an exogenous price. | |||
==Monopsonist in the labor market== | |||
If the firm is a perfect competitor in the goods market but is a [[monopsonist]] in the labor market — meaning that it is the only buyer of labor, so the amount it demands influences the wage rate — then its optimization problem is | |||
:<math> \text{Maximize} \,\, pQ - wL(w) - rK \,\, \text{with respect to} \,\, Q, \, w, \, \text{and} \, K</math> | |||
:<math> \text{subject to} </math> | |||
:<math>Q = f\,(L, K),</math> | |||
where ''L''(''w'') is the market labor supply function of workers which faces the firm. Here the firm cannot choose an amount of labor to demand independently of the wage rate, because the labor supply function links the quantity of labor that can be hired to the wage rate; therefore ''there is no labor demand function''. | |||
==See also== | |||
*[[Conditional factor demands]] | |||
*[[Labour_economics#Neoclassical_microeconomic_model_.E2.80.94_Demand|Neoclassical micro-economic model]] | |||
*[[Labour economics#Wage slavery|Wage slavery]] | |||
==References== | |||
{{reflist}} | |||
[[Category:Economics]] | |||
[[Category:Labor economics]] |
Revision as of 15:09, 8 January 2014
In economics, labor demand refers to the number of hours of hiring that an employer is willing to do based on the various exogenous (externally determined) variables it is faced with, such as the wage rate, the unit cost of capital, the market-determined selling price of its output, etc. The function specifying the quantity of labor that would be demanded at any of various possible values of these exogenous variables is called the labor demand function.[1]
Perfect competitor
The labor demand function of a competitive firm is determined by the following profit maximization problem:
where p is the exogenous selling price of the produced output, Q is the chosen quantity of output to be produced per month, w is the hourly wage rate paid to a worker, L is the number of labor hours hired (the quantity of labor demanded) per month, r is the cost of using a machine (capital) for an hour (the "rental rate"), K is the number of hours of machinery used (the quantity of capital demanded) per month, and f is the production function specifying the amount of output that can be produced using any of various combinations of quantities of labor and capital. This optimization problem involves simultaneously choosing the levels of labor, capital, and output. The resulting labor demand, capital demand, and output supply functions are of the general form
and
Ordinarily labor demand will be an increasing function of the product's selling price p (since a higher p makes it worthwhile to produce more output and to hire additional units of input in order to do so), and a decreasing function of w (since more expensive labor makes it worthwhile to hire less labor and produce less output). The rental rate of capital, r, has two conflicting effects: more expensive capital induces the firm to substitute away from physical capital usage and into more labor usage, contingent on any particular level of output; but the higher capital cost also induces the firm to produce less output, requiring less usage of both inputs. Depending on which effect predominates, labor demand could be either increasing or decreasing in r.
Monopolist
If the firm is a monopolist, its optimization problem is different because it cannot take its selling price as given: the more it produces, the lower will be the price it can obtain for each unit of output, according to the market demand curve for the product. So its profit-maximization problem is
where Q(p) is the market demand function for the product. The constraint equates the amount that can be sold to the amount produced. Here labor demand, capital demand, and the selling price are the choice variables, giving rise to the input demand functions
and the pricing function
There is no output supply function for a monopolist, because a supply function pre-supposes the existence of an exogenous price.
Monopsonist in the labor market
If the firm is a perfect competitor in the goods market but is a monopsonist in the labor market — meaning that it is the only buyer of labor, so the amount it demands influences the wage rate — then its optimization problem is
where L(w) is the market labor supply function of workers which faces the firm. Here the firm cannot choose an amount of labor to demand independently of the wage rate, because the labor supply function links the quantity of labor that can be hired to the wage rate; therefore there is no labor demand function.
See also
References
43 year old Petroleum Engineer Harry from Deep River, usually spends time with hobbies and interests like renting movies, property developers in singapore new condominium and vehicle racing. Constantly enjoys going to destinations like Camino Real de Tierra Adentro.
- ↑ Varian, Hal, 1992, Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd Ed., W.W. Norton & Company, Inc. New York.