(S)-N-acetyl-1-phenylethylamine hydrolase: Difference between revisions
en>Citation bot 1 m [Pu408]Add: issue. You can use this bot yourself. Report bugs here. |
en>Dcirovic |
||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
A '''Divisia index''' is a theoretical construct to create [[index number]] series for continuous-time data on prices and quantities of goods exchanged. | |||
It is designed to incorporate quantity and price changes over time from subcomponents which are measured in different units -- e.g. labor hours and equipment investment and materials purchases -- and to summarize these in a time series which summarizes the changes in quantities and/or prices. The resulting index number series is unitless, like other index numbers.<ref>Charles R. Hulten, 2008. "Divisia index" ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]'', 2nd Edition. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_D000174&edition=current&q=Divisia%20index%20&topicid=&result_number=1 Abstract].</ref> | |||
In practice, economic data are not measured in continuous time so when a series is said to be a Divisia index, it usually means the series follows a procedure that makes a close analogue in discrete time periods, usually the [[Törnqvist index]] procedure or the [[Fisher Ideal Index]] procedures.<ref name=diewert_ch2>Diewert, W.E. 1993. [http://faculty.arts.ubc.ca/ediewert/indexch2.pdf The early history of price index research]. Chapter 2 of ''Essays in Index Number Theory, Volume I'', W.E. Diewert and A.O. Nakamura, editors. Elsevier Science Publishers, B.V.</ref> | |||
== Uses == | |||
Divisia-type indices are used in these contexts for example: | |||
* Multifactor productivity calculations use [[quantity index]]es which incorporate changes in the expenditure share and overall quality of the underlying goods, and are then multiplied by prices. A Divisia index of all measured outputs can be divided by a Divisia index of all measured inputs to get an estimate of the productivity change that occurred apart from the changes in inputs. | |||
* Aggregation of different monetary pools, e.g. cash and credit card borrowing and different currencies. Here the pools of various monetary aggregates are treated as a quantities, and the prices are usually taken as fixed, but their ''weights'' vary -- for example, the [[Bank of England]] has an index of the money stock that is available for transactions. The index weights the various money pools by the likelihood they will be used in transactions in the near run -- physical cash and checking accounts are ready to be spent, whereas long term bonds which are not ready to be spent. The interest rate received on the various money pools is a measure of the weight; pounds in cash count more than pounds in bonds. Movement of money from one form to another affects the index whereas it would not affect a simple sum of the money stock; thus the index is more useful to track the money ready-to-transact than a sum would be.<ref>[http://moneyterms.co.uk/divisia/ Divisia money supply index] at moneyterms.co.uk</ref> The U.S. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis computes similar [[Divisia monetary aggregates index|Divisia monetary aggregate indexes]].<ref>[http://research.stlouisfed.org/msi/index.html Monetary Services Index] at Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Research pages</ref> | |||
* Some [[price index]]es incorporate changes in the quantity, expenditure share, and quality on various underlying goods as well as the changes in prices for them, although the term ''Divisia index'' is not often used in the official descriptions of consumer price indexes, producer price indexes, or personal consumption indexes. Various price indexes use the Tornqvist, Fisher-Ideal, or other procedures which produce close approximations to a Divisia index. | |||
== Data input == | |||
The theory of the Divisia indexes of goods (say, inputs to a production process, or prices for consumer goods) uses these components as data input: | |||
* there are ''n'' inputs, where ''n'' is a whole number | |||
* ''t'' is a continuous index of time, starting at 0 | |||
* <math>p_{i}(t)</math> are continuous series of price data for each input from i=1 to i=n | |||
* <math>q_{i}(t)</math> are continuous series of quantity data for each input. The shifting importance of the various goods are measured, for prices, by the changes in quantities, and for quantities by the changes in prices. One might therefore use something different from literal price or quantity to measure these importance/weights. | |||
* Arbitrary index based levels P(0) and Q(0) are selected -- in practice, 1, or 100, or one is chosen in this way and the other is chosen to meet the criteria that P(0)*Q(0) equals the actual amount of the transactions, or value, exchanged: | |||
::<math>\sum_{i} p(0)*q(0) = P(0)Q(0) .</math> | |||
Then a price index ''P(t)'' and quantity index ''Q(t)'' are the solution to a differential equation and if ''P(0)'' and ''Q(0)'' were chosen suitably the series summarize all transactions in the sense that for all t:<ref name=diewert_ch2/> | |||
:<math>\sum_{i} p(t)*q(t) = P(t)Q(t).</math> | |||
== Discrete-time approximations == | |||
In practices, discrete time analogues to Divisia indexes are the ones computed and used. | |||
To define and compute changes in a discrete time index closely analogous to a Divisia index from time 0 to time 1: | |||
* Gather price and quantity for each component, using measures that have been adjusted for quality change if possible | |||
* Compute cost/price/expenditure fractions for each component at time 1 and time 2. Average the time-1 and time-2 fractions for each component. Use those averages as the 'weights' for the component. Define the weights to be averages of expenditures shares or cost shares over the period of change: | |||
::<math>s_{j,t}^{*}=\frac{1}{2}(s_{j,t}+s_{j,t-1})</math> | |||
:(See, for example, [[Divisia monetary aggregates index]].) | |||
* The value of the index at time 0 is an arbitrary normalization, usually chosen to be 1 or 100 which makes it easier to make quick inferences about overall fractional or percentage changes. | |||
== History == | |||
Divisia indexes were proposed and analyzed formally by [[François Divisia]] in 1926, and discussed in related 1925 and 1928 works.<ref name=diewert_ch2/><ref>• Divisia, F. 1925. "L'indice monétaire et la théorie de la monnaie." ''Revue d'écon. polit.'', XXXIX, Nos. 4, 5, 6: 842-61, 980-1008, 1121-51.<br/> • Divisia, F. 1926. "L'indice monétaire et la théorie de la monnaie." ''Revue d'écon. polit.'', LX, No. 1: 49-81.<br/> • Divisia, F. ''L'économie rationnelle'' (1928) Paris: Gaston Doin et Cie.</ref> | |||
== Notes == | |||
<references/> | |||
[[Category:Index numbers]] | |||
[[Category:Price index theory]] | |||
[[Category:Econometrics]] | |||
[[it:Indice di Divisia]] |
Revision as of 18:28, 13 May 2013
A Divisia index is a theoretical construct to create index number series for continuous-time data on prices and quantities of goods exchanged.
It is designed to incorporate quantity and price changes over time from subcomponents which are measured in different units -- e.g. labor hours and equipment investment and materials purchases -- and to summarize these in a time series which summarizes the changes in quantities and/or prices. The resulting index number series is unitless, like other index numbers.[1]
In practice, economic data are not measured in continuous time so when a series is said to be a Divisia index, it usually means the series follows a procedure that makes a close analogue in discrete time periods, usually the Törnqvist index procedure or the Fisher Ideal Index procedures.[2]
Uses
Divisia-type indices are used in these contexts for example:
- Multifactor productivity calculations use quantity indexes which incorporate changes in the expenditure share and overall quality of the underlying goods, and are then multiplied by prices. A Divisia index of all measured outputs can be divided by a Divisia index of all measured inputs to get an estimate of the productivity change that occurred apart from the changes in inputs.
- Aggregation of different monetary pools, e.g. cash and credit card borrowing and different currencies. Here the pools of various monetary aggregates are treated as a quantities, and the prices are usually taken as fixed, but their weights vary -- for example, the Bank of England has an index of the money stock that is available for transactions. The index weights the various money pools by the likelihood they will be used in transactions in the near run -- physical cash and checking accounts are ready to be spent, whereas long term bonds which are not ready to be spent. The interest rate received on the various money pools is a measure of the weight; pounds in cash count more than pounds in bonds. Movement of money from one form to another affects the index whereas it would not affect a simple sum of the money stock; thus the index is more useful to track the money ready-to-transact than a sum would be.[3] The U.S. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis computes similar Divisia monetary aggregate indexes.[4]
- Some price indexes incorporate changes in the quantity, expenditure share, and quality on various underlying goods as well as the changes in prices for them, although the term Divisia index is not often used in the official descriptions of consumer price indexes, producer price indexes, or personal consumption indexes. Various price indexes use the Tornqvist, Fisher-Ideal, or other procedures which produce close approximations to a Divisia index.
Data input
The theory of the Divisia indexes of goods (say, inputs to a production process, or prices for consumer goods) uses these components as data input:
- there are n inputs, where n is a whole number
- t is a continuous index of time, starting at 0
- are continuous series of price data for each input from i=1 to i=n
- are continuous series of quantity data for each input. The shifting importance of the various goods are measured, for prices, by the changes in quantities, and for quantities by the changes in prices. One might therefore use something different from literal price or quantity to measure these importance/weights.
- Arbitrary index based levels P(0) and Q(0) are selected -- in practice, 1, or 100, or one is chosen in this way and the other is chosen to meet the criteria that P(0)*Q(0) equals the actual amount of the transactions, or value, exchanged:
Then a price index P(t) and quantity index Q(t) are the solution to a differential equation and if P(0) and Q(0) were chosen suitably the series summarize all transactions in the sense that for all t:[2]
Discrete-time approximations
In practices, discrete time analogues to Divisia indexes are the ones computed and used. To define and compute changes in a discrete time index closely analogous to a Divisia index from time 0 to time 1:
- Gather price and quantity for each component, using measures that have been adjusted for quality change if possible
- Compute cost/price/expenditure fractions for each component at time 1 and time 2. Average the time-1 and time-2 fractions for each component. Use those averages as the 'weights' for the component. Define the weights to be averages of expenditures shares or cost shares over the period of change:
- (See, for example, Divisia monetary aggregates index.)
- The value of the index at time 0 is an arbitrary normalization, usually chosen to be 1 or 100 which makes it easier to make quick inferences about overall fractional or percentage changes.
History
Divisia indexes were proposed and analyzed formally by François Divisia in 1926, and discussed in related 1925 and 1928 works.[2][5]
Notes
- ↑ Charles R. Hulten, 2008. "Divisia index" The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition. Abstract.
- ↑ 2.0 2.1 2.2 Diewert, W.E. 1993. The early history of price index research. Chapter 2 of Essays in Index Number Theory, Volume I, W.E. Diewert and A.O. Nakamura, editors. Elsevier Science Publishers, B.V.
- ↑ Divisia money supply index at moneyterms.co.uk
- ↑ Monetary Services Index at Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Research pages
- ↑ • Divisia, F. 1925. "L'indice monétaire et la théorie de la monnaie." Revue d'écon. polit., XXXIX, Nos. 4, 5, 6: 842-61, 980-1008, 1121-51.
• Divisia, F. 1926. "L'indice monétaire et la théorie de la monnaie." Revue d'écon. polit., LX, No. 1: 49-81.
• Divisia, F. L'économie rationnelle (1928) Paris: Gaston Doin et Cie.