Force spectroscopy: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>Compsim
m Undid revision 549141343: papercore link is no spam but link to free and open scientific summary paper (in contrast to restricted journal access)
en>Tom.Reding
m Gen fixes (page/s, endash, &nbsp, et al., unicodify, concising wikilinks, etc.), ref cleanup using AWB
 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{About|the economic measure|the index of scientific prolificacy|H-index}}
Human being who wrote the short post is called Roberto Ledbetter and his wife does not have to like it at every bit. In his professional life he can be a people manager. He's always [http://browse.deviantart.com/?q=loved+living loved living] to Guam and he gives you everything that he circumstances there. The favorite hobby for him and / or his kids is for [http://www.answers.com/topic/watering+gardens watering gardens] . but he's been ingesting on new things a short time ago. He's been working on his website for some spare time now. Check it out in the open here: http://prometeu.net<br><br>Have a look at my webpage - [http://prometeu.net clash of clans generator]
{{Refimprove|date=April 2009}}
 
The '''Herfindahl index''' (also known as '''Herfindahl–Hirschman Index''', or '''HHI''') is a measure of the size of [[corporation|firm]]s in relation to the [[industry]] and an indicator of the amount of competition among them.  Named after economists [[Orris C. Herfindahl]] and [[Albert O. Hirschman]], it is an [[economics|economic]] concept widely applied in [[competition law]], [[antitrust]]<ref name="MergerGuidelines">''2010 Merger Guidelines'' § 5.3</ref> and also technology management.<ref>Catherine Liston-Hayes, [[Alan Pilkington]], [http://dx.doi.org/10.3152/147154304781780190 “Inventive Concentration: An Analysis of Fuel Cell Patents,”] Science and Public Policy, (2004). Vol. 31, No. 1, p.15-25.</ref> It is defined as the sum of the squares of the [[market share]]s of the 50 largest firms (or summed over all the firms if there are fewer than 50)<ref>[http://www.pearsoned.ca/highered/divisions/bande/parkin/solutions/soluch09.pdf Chapter 9 Organizing Production]</ref> within the industry, where the market shares are expressed as fractions. The result is proportional to the average market share, weighted by market share. As such, it can range from 0 to 1.0, moving from a huge number of very small firms to a single [[monopoly|monopolistic]] producer. Increases in the Herfindahl index generally indicate a decrease in competition and an increase of [[market power]], whereas decreases indicate the opposite. Alternatively, if whole percentages are used, the index ranges from 0 to 10,000 "points".  For example, an index of .25 is the same as 2,500 points.
 
The major benefit of the Herfindahl index in relationship to such measures as the [[concentration ratio]] is that it gives more weight to larger firms.
 
The measure is essentially equivalent to the [[Simpson diversity index]] used in ecology and to the inverse participation ratio (IPR) in physics.
 
==Example==
For instance, two cases in which the six largest firms produce 90% of the goods in a market:
 
* Case 1: All six firms produce 15% each, and
* Case 2: One firm produces 80% while the five others produce 2% each.
 
We will assume that the remaining 10% of output is divided among 10 equally sized producers.
 
The six-firm concentration ratio would equal 90% for both case 1 and case 2.  But the first case would promote significant competition, where the second case approaches [[monopoly]]. The Herfindahl index for these two situations makes the lack of competition in the second case strikingly clear:
 
* Case 1: Herfindahl index = (0.15<sup>2</sup>+0.15<sup>2</sup>+0.15<sup>2</sup>+0.15<sup>2</sup>+0.15<sup>2</sup>+0.15<sup>2</sup>) + (0.01<sup>2</sup>+0.01<sup>2</sup>+0.01<sup>2</sup>+0.01<sup>2</sup>+0.01<sup>2</sup>+0.01<sup>2</sup>+0.01<sup>2</sup>+0.01<sup>2</sup>+0.01<sup>2</sup>+0.01<sup>2</sup>)= 0.136 (13.6%)
* Case 2: Herfindahl index = 0.80<sup>2</sup> + 5 * 0.02<sup>2</sup> + 10 * 0.01<sup>2</sup> = 0.643 (64.3%)
 
This behavior rests in the fact that the market shares are squared prior to being summed, giving additional weight to firms with larger size.
 
The index involves taking the market share of the respective market competitors, squaring it, and adding them together (e.g. in the market for X, company A has 30%, B, C, D, E and F have 10% each and G through to Z have 1% each). If the resulting figure is above a certain threshold then economists consider the market to have a high concentration (e.g. market X's concentration is 0.142 or 14.2%). This threshold is considered to be 0.25 in the U.S.,<ref name="MergerGuidelines" /> while the EU prefers to focus on the level of change, for instance that concern is raised if there is a 0.025 change when the index already shows a concentration of 0.1.<ref>However, it gets far more complicated than that. See para. 16-21 ''Guidelines on horizontal mergers''</ref> So to take the example, if in market X company B (with 10% market share) suddenly bought out the shares of company C (with 10% also) then this new market concentration would make the index jump to 0.162. Here it can be seen that it would not be relevant for merger law in the U.S. (being under 0.18) or in the EU (because there is not a change over 0.025).
 
==Formula==
 
:<math>H =\sum_{i=1}^N s_i^2</math>
 
where ''s<sub>i</sub>'' is the market share of firm ''i'' in the market, and ''N'' is the number of firms. Thus, in a market with two firms that each have 50 percent market share, the Herfindahl index equals
0.50<sup>2</sup>+0.50<sup>2</sup> = 1/2.
 
The Herfindahl Index (''H'') ranges from 1/''N'' to one, where ''N'' is the number of firms in the market. Equivalently, if percents are used as whole numbers, as in 75 instead of 0.75, the index can range up to 100<sup>2</sup>, or 10,000.
 
A HHI index below 0.01 (or 100) indicates a highly competitive index.<br>
A HHI index below 0.15 (or 1,500) indicates an unconcentrated index.<br>
A HHI index between 0.15 to 0.25 (or 1,500 to 2,500) indicates moderate concentration.<br>
A HHI index above 0.25 (above 2,500) indicates high concentration [http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg-2010.html].
 
A small index indicates a competitive industry with no dominant players. If all firms have an equal share the reciprocal of the index shows the number of firms in the industry. When firms have unequal shares, the reciprocal of the index indicates the "equivalent" number of firms in the industry. Using case 2, we find that the market structure is equivalent to having 1.55521 firms of the same size.
 
There is also a normalised Herfindahl index. Whereas the Herfindahl index ranges from 1/N to one, the normalized Herfindahl index ranges from 0 to 1. It is computed as:
 
:<math>H^* = {\left ( H - 1/N \right ) \over 1-1/N }</math>
 
where again, N is the number of firms in the market, and H is the usual Herfindahl Index, as above.
 
==Problems==
The usefulness of this statistic to detect and stop harmful monopolies however is directly dependent on a proper definition of a particular market (which hinges primarily on the notion of substitutability).
 
* For example, if the statistic were to look at a hypothetical financial services industry as a whole, and found that it contained 6 main firms with 15% market share apiece, then the industry would look non-monopolistic. However, one of those firms handles 90% of the checking and savings accounts and physical branches (and overcharges for them because of its monopoly), and the others primarily do commercial banking and investments. In this scenario, people would be suffering due to a market dominance by one firm; the market is not properly defined because checking accounts are not substitutable with commercial and investment banking. The problems of defining a market work the other way as well. To take another example, one cinema may have 90% of the movie market, but if movie theatres compete against video stores, pubs and nightclubs then people are less likely to be suffering due to market dominance.
 
* Another typical problem in defining the market is choosing a geographic scope. For example, firms may have 20% market share each, but may occupy five areas of the country in which they are monopoly providers and thus do not compete against each other. A service provider or manufacturer in one city is not necessarily substitutable with a service provider or manufacturer in another city, depending on the importance of being local for the business&mdash;for example, telemarketing services are rather global in scope, while shoe repair services are local.
 
The United States Federal anti-trust authorities such as the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission use the Herfindahl index as a screening tool to determine whether a proposed merger is likely to raise antitrust concerns. Increases of over 0.01 generally provoke scrutiny, although this varies from case to case. The [[United States Department of Justice Antitrust Division|Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice]] considers Herfindahl indices between 0.15 and 0.25 to be "moderately concentrated" and indices above 0.25 to be "highly concentrated".<ref>{{cite web|publisher=[[USDOJ]]|url=http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hhi.html|title=Herfindahl–Hirschman Index|accessdate=4 May 2012}}</ref>  As the [[market concentration]] increases, [[competition]] and [[efficiency (economics)|efficiency]] decrease and the chances of [[collusion]] and [[monopoly]] increase.
 
For formation of effective market economy and competition economic conditions in different sectors of market, the developing countries also use Herfindahl index (see [[Revaz Lordkipanidze]]).
 
==Intuition==
When all the firms in an industry have equal market shares, H = 1/N.  The Herfindahl is correlated with the number of firms in an industry because its lower bound when there are N firms is 1/N.  An industry with 3 firms cannot have a lower Herfindahl than an industry with 20 firms when firms have equal market shares. But as market shares of the 20-firm industry diverge from equality the Herfindahl can exceed that of the equal-market-share 3-firm industry (e.g., if one firm has 81% of the market and the remaining 19 have 1% each H=0.658).  A higher Herfindahl signifies a less competitive industry.
 
The Herfindahl index is also a widely used metrics for economic concentration.<ref>{{cite book|last=Lovett|first=William|title=Banking and Financial Institutions Law in a Nutshell|year=1988|publisher=West Publishing Co.}}</ref> In portfolio theory, the Herfindahl index is related to the effective number of positions held in a portfolio. More precisely, this number is Neff = 1/H,<ref>{{cite journal|last=Bouchaud|first=Jean-Philippe|coauthors=Potters, Aguilar|title=Missing Information and Asset Allocation|year=1997|url=http://xxx.lanl.gov/cond-mat/9707042}}</ref> where H is computed as the sum of the squares of the proportion of market value invested in each security. A low H-index implies a very diversified portfolio: as an example, a portfolio with H = 0.01 is equivalent to a portfolio with Neff=100 equally weighted positions. The H-index has been shown to be one of the most efficient measures of portfolio diversification.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Woerheide|first=Walt|coauthors=Persson, Don|journal=FINANCIAL SERVICES REVIEW|year=1993|volume=2|issue=2|pages=73–85}}</ref>
 
==Decomposition==
If we suppose that ''N'' firms share all the market, then the index can be expressed as <math>H =\frac1N+N V</math> where ''N'' is the number of firms, as above, and ''V'' is the [[variance|statistical variance]] of the firm shares, defined as <math>V=\frac{\sum_{i=1}^N\left(s_i-1/N\right)^2}N</math>. If all firms have equal (identical) shares (that is, if the market structure is completely ''[[symmetric]]'', in which case ''s<sub>i</sub>'' = 1/''N'' for all ''i'') then ''V'' is zero and ''H'' equals 1/''N''. If the number of firms in the market is held constant, then a higher variance due to a higher level of asymmetry between firms' shares (that is, a higher ''share dispersion'') will result in a higher index value. See Brown and Warren-Boulton (1988), also see Warren-Boulton (1990).{{Citation needed|reason=specific reference needed for the whole paragraph|date=November 2011}}
 
==See also==
*[[Concentration ratio]]
*[[Diversity index]]
*[[Market concentration]]
*[[Market form]]s
*[[Microeconomics]]
*[[Market dominance strategies]]
*[[N50 statistic]] - a measure of concentration used in genomics
 
==References==
{{reflist}}
 
==Further reading==
*{{cite journal |last=Brown |first=Donald M. |authorlink= |coauthors=Warren-Boulton, Frederick R. |title=Testing the Structure-Competition Relationship on Cross-Sectional Firm Data |version=Discussion paper 88-6 |pages= |publisher=Economic Analysis Group, U.S. Department of Justice |date=May 11, 1988 |url= }}
*{{cite journal |last=Capozza |first=Dennis R. |authorlink= |coauthors=Lee, Sohan |year=1996 |month= |title=Portfolio Characteristics and Net Asset Values in REITs |journal=The Canadian Journal of Economics|volume=29 |issue=Special Issue: Part 2 |pages=S520&ndash;S526 |doi=10.2307/136100|publisher=Blackwell Publishing |jstor=136100 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Hirschman |first=Albert O. |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1964 |month= |title=The Paternity of an Index |journal=The American Economic Review |volume=54 |issue=5 |pages=761 |doi= |jstor= 1818582|publisher=American Economic Association }}
*{{cite journal |last=Kwoka |first=John E., Jr. |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1977 |month= |title=Large Firm Dominance and Price-Cost Margins in Manufacturing Industries |journal=Southern Economic Journal |volume=44 |issue=1 |pages=183&ndash;189 |doi=10.2307/1057315|publisher=Southern Economic Association |jstor=1057315 }}
*{{cite book |title=The Law and Economics of Competition Policy |chapter=Implications of U.S. Experience with Horizontal Mergers and Takeovers for Canadian Competition Policy |last=Warren-Boulton |first=Frederick R. |authorlink= |editor=Mathewson, G. Franklin ''et al.'' (eds.) |year=1990 |publisher=The Fraser Institute |location=Vancouver, B.C. |isbn=0-88975-121-8 |pages= }}
 
==External links==
* [http://wits.worldbank.org World Integrated Trade Solution], ''Calculate Herfindahl-Hirschman Index using UNSD COMTRADE data''
*[http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/testimony/hhi.htm US Department of Justice example and market concentration cutoffs].
*[http://www.unclaw.com/chin/teaching/antitrust/herfindahl.htm Herfindahl-Hirschman Index Calculator]. Web tool for calculating pre- and post-merger Herfindahl index.
*[http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hmg-2010.html Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines]. More detailed information about mergers, market concentration, and competition (from the [[United States Department of Justice|Department of Justice]]).
 
[[Category:Econometrics]]
[[Category:Microeconomics]]
[[Category:Monopoly (economics)]]
[[Category:Imperfect competition]]
 
[[it:Indice di concentrazione#Indice di concentrazione di Herfindahl-Hirschman]]

Latest revision as of 05:59, 26 December 2014

Human being who wrote the short post is called Roberto Ledbetter and his wife does not have to like it at every bit. In his professional life he can be a people manager. He's always loved living to Guam and he gives you everything that he circumstances there. The favorite hobby for him and / or his kids is for watering gardens . but he's been ingesting on new things a short time ago. He's been working on his website for some spare time now. Check it out in the open here: http://prometeu.net

Have a look at my webpage - clash of clans generator